Wednesday, June 5, 2019

Impact of Swedens Integration to the EU

Impact of Swedens Integration to the EUThe Geography of European IntegrationAlexandrou Efstratia-CeliaCategory ASweden and its experience from the work at of integration and enlargementThe enlargement process has been a top priority for the European Union during the commencement exercise years of the 21th century. Swedens accession was in 1995 along with Austria and Finland, when these countries became members of the European Union. However, even before this accession, Sweden as well as the other two countries- followed a path of increasing commitment to the European integration process from a free trade arrangement, via the European Economic Area (the EFTA states affiliation to the Internal securities industry), to full EU membership. Moreover, Swedens economy was highly internationalized, and at the aforesaid(prenominal) time quite similar to its EU neighbors when it came to income and structure. Keeping this in mind, joining the EU in 1995 was non an actual large step.At the turn of the year 1991- 1992, Swedish economy along with others- had been set about a downturn for about two years. The Maastricht negotiation was in its final stage but the Internal Market Program was also a fundamental theme on the political agenda, in the European Community as well as in the EFTA (European Free Trade Association) states. In 1992 the Internal Market was formally accomplished and the EEA (European Economic Area) agreement was signed. It was after the collapse of the Communist bloc that made neutrality a problem and full accession to the EC had become a primary political objective. In the end of 1992, the Swedish currency fell dramatically, with a variety of consequences on exports (Central Bank, Sweden, 1996). Following the above, a breaker point of low inflation began. In January 1994, Sweden entered the Internal Market through the EEA agreement. The same year, a referendum brought EU rewards to the public debate, and in January 1995 Sweden became members of t he EU.While entering the European Union, renowned expectations were held, both in positive and negative legal injury. Firstly, the situation for small and medium sized enterprises (SMEs) and the people working for them could be of particular interest concerning the integration process. Secondly, from EUs point of view, as well as from Swedish policy makers, small firms were relied upon to create employment and a dynamic economy (Commission of the EC, 1995). At the same time, the Internal Market is a project of increasing scale, in markets and in production. However, when it comes to smaller firms they could be much vulnerable, as their capacity to detect and respond to environmental and societal change could be low or inadequate (d Amboise and Muldowney, 1988). So in order for integration not to be beneficial for large firms only, measures dumbfound been taken aiming to improve the situation for SMEs in the Internal Market. In spite of smaller firms resource situation being cri tical -having to do with distances, languages, cultural and administrative differences etc-, nevertheless, integration measures could also be beneficial for them as they can reduce crucial thresholds.In the field of manufacturing, the actual degree of integration, for example measured as the importance of international transactions, is relatively high. Although numerous types of obstacles to transactions between member states of the EU ar reduced, while preconditions for economic activity are harmonized, in that location is a strong potential for further integration that we cant overlook. Therefore, following a countrys entry into a common market, trade was pass judgment to achieve certain increase as well as competition would be able to reach new areas of the economy.According to Bonnedahls questionnaire, when it came to consequences from integration, more firms pertain competition more often as a threat earlier than as an opportunity. Furthermore, distribution issues, includi ng goods handling and certification were characterized as facilitated regarding lineage inside the EU, whereas business with third countries had become more difficult or costly. In addition to the above, competition from low cost producers in Eastern Europe is an important issue with many firms tending to move their production in lower cost countries outside Sweden. The beneficial part had to do with the business interaction with the EU as it was after the integration more positive (Bonnedahl, 2004). Additionally, in 1996 already- the firms had higher sales to EU markets, which means that when integration measures succeed in reducing differences between countries thither a decrease is expected in the need for a successive build-up of resources and experience. Another consequence is that some of the possibilities for protection on the domestic market pass on be weakened. Last but not least the endurance of certain differences could be an advantage in smaller firms, whereas in large multinational firms is no problem at all as they can make more out of a single market.In conclusion, although responses to the general question of whether consequences from integration intimate that the Internal Markets impact has been positive and negative at the same time and while economic stability difficulties have arise we should not overlook the main advantage which is the increasing commitment to foreign markets, of which some could be attributed to the formal integration process as well as the pose to EU trade which has also become more positive.ReferencesAbrams, R.K. et.al. (1990). The Impact of the European Communitys Internal Market on the EFTA. IMF, Washington, dec.Barnes, I. Barnes, P.M. (1995) The enlarged European Union. Longman, London.Blomstrm, M. Lipsey, R.E. (1994) Norden i EU Vad sger ekonomerna om effekterna? SNS, Stockholm.Bonnedahl, K.J. (2004) The Integration of Sweden to the European Internal Market A process examined through data from small and mediu m sized firms 1992, 1996 and 2004Bonnedahl, K.J. (1999) En fretagsstrategisk analys av ekonomisk integration Konsekvenser av Europas inre marknad fr svenska mindre tillverkande fretag. Dissertation Ume university.Central Bank (Riksbanken). Penning- och valutapolitik 1/1996. Stockholm, 1996.Commission of the EC. (1995(a)) COM(95) 502 final. Hantverkssektorn och smfretagen nyckeln till tillvxt och sysselsttning i Europa. Brussels.Commission of the EC. (1995(b)) CSE(95) 2087. SMEs a dynamic source of employment, growth and competitiveness in the European Union. Brussels.Commission of the EC. (1996) COM(96) 98 final. Att till fullo utnyttja de europeiska sm och medelstora fretagens mjligheter till sysselsttning, tillvxt och konkurrenskraft. Brussels.There is determinism in the integration experience of EU economies less advanced will be affected negatively by competition, more advanced will be favored.The phrase economic integration could be described as a way by which countries aim to increase their aim of welfare. Regional economic integration may appear in different forms based on the degree of integration between countries. The four main types of regional arrangements are free trade agreements, customs unions, common markets and single markets. Free trade agreement is a preferential trade arrangement in which taxes fees among members do not exist. In a customs union, members additionally opt for a common external tax. Common market is about members permitting free, or at least, greatly increased, factor mobility within the market. The single market is the highest form of economic integration, stipulating that all producers and consumers are governed by exactly the same rules, implying that they must be treated evenly in all parts of the market. An even deeper level of integration is reached if countries within a single market agree to coordinate their economic policies (Economic Union) or if countries within a single market agree to common policies in almo st every sector (Political Union).When observing the process of European economic integration the first thing that pops up is that cohesion countries have go considerably closer to Community average in terms of per capita GDP and then -following the economic crisis moved away- again. Typically, the EU measures cohesion as inter-regional differences in labour market conditions and average income per head. This approach is not without its problems. Firstly, much(prenominal) a focus can overlook the uttermost of intra-regional inequalities (Collier, 1994), for instance, has pointed out that per capita income requirements for a region can be close to EU average but can hide quite marked intra-regional differences. Secondly there is a fundamental problem in defining and measuring cohesion by reference to regional indicators measures of interregional inequality depend on the regional boundaries which are selected (O Donnell, 1993).The economic performance of some regions improved signi ficantly during the 1980s. However, there is no evidence proving there is a trend towards the elimination of disparities. Indeed, disparities between member states such as Spain, Italy and the UK have increased significantly over recent years. Regional inequality remains entrenched in Europe and go forms to be growing rather than diminishing. The problem is to put into perspective when it is recognized that regional GDP per capita disparities in the EU are twice as high as in the US and unemployment disparities three times higher than in the US (CEC 1991).These spatial disparities are supposed to be tackled by the EUs various structural Funds, which grew in size and importance during the 1980s. The accession of the UK and Ireland extended the scale and nature of the regional problem within the EU. In particular the UK brought with it a number of crisis hit industrial regions. The UKs problems in this regard were particularly acute, but similar problems of concentrated industrial decline emerged in most northern member states during the 70s and the problem of converting regions in industrial decline became an important task of the ERDF. During the 1980s the accession of Greece and later Spain and Portugal brought new concern with cohesion, as did intensifying problems in the declining industrial regions. The Structural Funds were reformed in 1979 and 1984 as the Commission sought to increase the available resources and to improve the effectiveness of the funds. A more far-reaching reform of the Structural Funds occurred in 1988. This reform differed from the previous ones in so far as it was one aspect of the renewed impetus to economic integration, represented by the signing of the Single European Act.Another problem when it comes to EUs approach to cohesion is the faith it places in market forces to stimulate growth and see to its trickle down to the less developed regions. A wise expression of the EU approach to cohesion is the one given by Delors (1989) who rejected the imagination that there are inevitable winners or losers in the process of integration. Peripherality, for instance, is no longer described as a serious problem on the terms that transport costs are becoming, gradually, less important regarding the location of industrial production. New developments in telecommunications and increased capital mobility are seen to represent an opening up of the firms choices relative to the aspect of location, with the implication that this may benefit the less favoured regions. Delors concludes that the most important factor determining the distribution of industrial activity is effective supply-side policies, and for this readon he rejects regional employment and capital subsidies. The former, he argues, may give the wrong signal to those responsible for labour comptetitiveness while the latter may encourage inefficient investment.In conclusion, the question is not whether the proposals above are good or bad few would oppose them- but whether they are good enough in order to close the regional gap in Europe. It has to be asked, also, whether any positive gains resulting from EU regional policy in facilitating cohesion are complemented by EU policy actions designed to enhance European competitiveness. In my opinion, the evidence until now shows us that larger firms and advanced regions are being favored. Lets hope that eventually the opposite will happen.ReferencesDelors, J., (1989). Report on economic and monetary union in the European Community. Committee for the study of economic and monetary union.European Cohesion Policy 2014-2020. European CommisionCategory BDepartment of Planning and Regional DevelopmentAlexandrou Efstratia-Celia

No comments:

Post a Comment

Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.